David E. Bernstein
excerpted from: David E. Bernstein, The Law and
Economics of Post-civil War Restrictions on Interstate Migration by
African-Americans, 76 Texas Law Review 781-847, 781 (March, 1998) (406
Footnotes)
"A man has a right to go anywhere in this country he may
choose." --R.A. "Peg Leg" Williams, Southern emigrant
agent
In Williams v. Fears, the Supreme Court upheld a racist statute that
imposed a prohibitive license fee on interstate labor recruiters known
as "emigrant agents." The result in Williams negatively
affected the lives of millions of African-Americans, yet, for reasons
explained in detail in this Article, the case has been doomed to almost
total obscurity.
From the end of the Civil War until Williams, emigrant agents played
a key role in encouraging and financing African-American migration
within the United States. Because many rural African-Americans
"were too poor to go very far without aid and because they lacked
ready access to information about opportunities in distant places,"
they had little choice but to rely on labor recruiters.
Emigrant agents lowered the information costs of migration by using
their resources to advertise distant opportunities. Agents also often
subsidized the economic costs of migration by either paying for or
advancing the money for the migrants' train tickets. The agents
sometimes even retired debts their recruits owed to plantation owners.
Emigrant agent laws greatly restricted such activity. By using
taxation to essentially prohibit agents from engaging in their
profession, these laws raised both the economic and information costs of
migration. As intended, the added costs made it more difficult for rural
African-Americans to migrate, particularly in large groups.
Group migrations were significant for several reasons. First, such
migrations were sometimes a form of political protest, one of the few
forms of protest in which disenfranchised African-Americans could
engage. African-Americans frequently deserted regions in response to
lynchings and other forms of white lawlessness, or in response to
unfavorable legislation. African-Americans would move to places where
they were relatively well treated or had relatively good economic
prospects. Second, in the era before the welfare state, emigrant agents
helped groups of destitute African-Americans flee areas devastated by
flood, drought, or boll weevils and other pests. Finally, and perhaps
most important, mass migration, and even the threat of such migration,
was crucial to improving the treatment of African-Americans by white
Southerners. In response to large-scale migrations, many farmers raised
wages, improved the living and working conditions of African-Americans,
and, with the cooperation of local and state government, granted
African-Americans greater educational opportunities and greater
protection in their property and person.
The body of this Article discusses Williams v. Fears in the context
of the law and economics of emigrant agent laws, and the "usable
history" that one can glean from the history of such laws. Part I
discusses the development of free labor markets in the South after the
Civil War, and reviews attempts by Southern whites to stifle such
markets in order to maintain a docile, inexpensive supply of
African-American labor. As economic theory would predict, white planters
were unable to form a successful voluntary cartel to stifle the free
labor market, so they turned to government coercion.
Part II discusses the origins of one example of government coercion,
emigrant agent laws. Emigrant agent laws were generally a reaction to
large-scale migrations of African-American workers in search of better
social, economic, and political conditions. Part II also discusses early
legal challenges to emigrant agent laws, some of which were surprisingly
successful. Two Southern state supreme courts held that emigrant agent
laws were unconstitutional.
Part III discusses the background to Williams v. Fears, and the
decision in that case. R.A. "Peg Leg" Williams, the named
party, was probably the most successful emigrant agent of his day. He
assisted tens of thousands of African-Americans in pursuing new economic
opportunities. Williams's arrest and conviction in Georgia for acting as
an emigrant agent and the United States Supreme Court's subsequent
ruling upholding the conviction led to a crackdown on emigrant agents
throughout the South. As a result, the poorest and most isolated
African-American workers found it particularly difficult to migrate and
escape their miserable conditions.
Given the devastating effects of emigrant agent laws, and the high
degree of interest in racial issues among legal scholars, it is
astounding that Williams has been almost completely neglected by legal
scholars. Part IV of this Article suggests that a major reason Williams
has been ignored is that legal historians are generally indifferent, if
not hostile, to economic reasoning. As explained in greater detail
below, because legal historians have disregarded economic reasoning,
they have virtually ignored subtle discriminatory economic regulations,
of which emigrant agent laws are an important example.
As discussed in detail in Part IV, the slighting of economic
reasoning by legal historians has impeded them from providing the
broader legal community with a usable history. The neglect of emigrant
agent laws, for example, has deprived legal scholars of information
highly relevant to several current controversies in legal academia.
First, the history of emigrant agent laws provides support for Richard
Epstein's controversial thesis that state action played a far larger
role in the economic oppression of African-Americans before the modern
civil rights era than is generally acknowledged. Second, the history of
constitutional litigation over emigrant agent laws shows that Lochnerian
"laissez-faire" jurisprudence could and at times did protect
minorities from hostile economic legislation. This history calls into
question the standard view that Lochnerian jurisprudence primarily
benefitted the wealthy and powerful at the expense of the poor. And,
third, the history of African-American migration discussed in this
Article calls into question the view commonly expressed in debates over
federalism that the historical decentralization of political power in
the United States was an unmitigated disaster for African-Americans. As
discussed in Part IV, at a time when the federal government was
generally hostile to African-American interests, decentralized
government allowed African-Americans to better their lot by migrating to
jurisdictions where relative economic opportunity or tolerance awaited.
[a1]. Assistant Professor, George Mason University School of Law.
E-mail: dbernste@wpgate.gmu.edu. |